Curbing Chinese corruption

China’s rapid growth has been fuelled by large investment and does not seem to be adversely affected by corruption.

CHINA BUSINESS AND BANKING
When corruption is chaotic, entrepreneurs face greater uncertainty, writes Mauro [Reuters]

When political scientists argue that corruption can sometimes help an economy grow, they have in mind a country like China. In an economy where several sectors are still shackled by pervasive regulations and controls, the payment of bribes in exchange for government permits can sometimes restore some semblance of a free market.

Indeed, while corruption is generally harmful to economic growth, there is a case to be made that in the years since China launched its transition to a market economy in the late 1970s, it was a necessary evil because of the country’s unique initial circumstances: rigid state control and limited international trade.

Power and People – China Rising

Today, however, President Xi Jinping’s drive against corruption is prompting a reconsideration of the effect of graft on the Chinese economy. In view of the country’s economic transformation and integration into the global economy, curbing corruption has now become even more necessary to sustain high economic growth.

Gigantic outlier

Most economists who have analysed the effects of corruption have found it to be detrimental to growth. In the first cross-country empirical study to examine this question, published 20 years ago, I showed that higher perceived corruption (based on surveys of investors) led to slower economic growth, in large part, through lower rates on private investments.

There was no link, however, in the cross-country data between corruption and declining public investment, perhaps because large infrastructure projects create ample opportunities for bribes.

As China has grown into a more internationally integrated, modern economy, pervasive corruption has become more harmful than beneficial.

 

Those results have been replicated by many researchers and corroborated by multiple studies based on different samples and techniques. Early work, including mine, was based on investor perceptions in the early 1980s and, thus, focused on market economies (understandably, the consulting firm that surveyed perceptions at the time did not analyse communist countries).

In any case, China, with its breakneck economic growth combined with perceptions of widespread corruption, has remained a gigantic outlier.

Two distinguishing features of the Chinese economy help to explain why it seems to be able to swim successfully against the current. First, China’s rapid economic growth has been fuelled by unusually large public investment, which, consistent with my own research, does not seem to be adversely affected by corruption.

Second, China’s strictly controlled society has given rise to well-organised corruption, which – as economists Andrei Shleifer and Robert Vishny argued in the early 1990s – is surely less harmful than the chaotic corruption experienced by, for example, the former Soviet countries during their early years of transition.

In China, entrepreneurs know whom to bribe and how much to pay, and they can be reasonably confident that, in exchange, they will be able to undertake their investment. In contrast, when corruption is chaotic, entrepreneurs face greater uncertainty: Paying a bribe to one official is no guarantee that other officials will not demand a payoff as well.


RELATED: China’s grand parade: Revenge of history


There is little doubt, however, that corruption has been rampant in China. In addition to the collection of bribes and the “sale” of promotions in the army and government, investigative journalists have documented that senior officials in China – as in many other countries – hold sizable stakes in valuable companies, often through investments and accounts concealed under the names of relatives and friends. 

Interestingly, the value of these companies may well have risen once the rumours spread that powerful officials had become associated with them.

Future challenges

It is conceivable that, without corruption and cronyism, China’s progress towards a market economy would not have been politically sustainable. By allowing government officials to have a stake in the country’s economic growth, it became easier to liberalise the economy and open the doors to international trade, one of the keys to China’s economic success.

undefined

But, as China has grown into a more internationally integrated and modern economy, pervasive corruption has become more harmful than beneficial.

The leadership may have come to the conclusion that, from the standpoint of political sustainability (and discounting the possibility of internecine power struggles), too many government officials among the “haves” would alienate the “have-not” ordinary citizens.

From an economic standpoint, with China increasingly exposed to the discipline of international trade and facing an economic slowdown, the argument for reining in corruption is as strong as ever. As my colleague Nicholas Lardy’s convincing analysis shows, China’s economic performance has been increasingly market-driven rather than state-driven, and private firms will provide the major source of growth in the years ahead. But this requires that the private sector be unimpeded by corruption.

Unfortunately, high-profile arrests, like those carried out in China in recent years, are insufficient to curb corruption in a lasting manner.


RELATED: China’s economy: Back to reality


Reducing pervasive government intervention in the economy and encouraging greater competition would reduce the near-monopolistic rents that create the incentives for corruption in the first place. This will require cutting red tape and deregulating the economy.

China’s primary political challenge in the near future will be to convince government officials to accept a growing entrepreneurial class who is richer than they are, while continuing to reform the economy and foster the development of the private sector.

The views expressed in this article are the author’s own and do not necessarily reflect Al Jazeera’s editorial policy.

Paolo Mauro is a senior fellow at the Peterson Institute for International Economics.

Copyright: Project Syndicate 2015 – Curbing Chinese Corruption